Resources and Population: A Wager

By Julian L. Simon

copperMany natural scientists such as physicists Murray Gell-Mann, William Shockley, and Andrei Sakharov have worried about human population size and growth. Henry Kendall, speaking for the Union of Concerned Scientists (including 99 Nobelists), asks nations to "stabilize population growth." A 1993 Science Summit on World Population, organized by the U.S. National Academy of Sciences with 59 other scientific academies (including Albania, Cuba, and Mongolia) stated: "Humanity is approaching a crisis point with respect to the interlocking issues of population, environment, and development" because "The Earth is finite."

Yet, almost every measure of material and environmental human welfare in the United States and in the world shows improvement rather than -deterioration. The long range trends are examined in 50 articles in The State of Humanity (Basil Blackwell, 1996). These are some of the findings:

  • On average, people throughout the world live longer and eat better than ever before. After a millennia of almost no improvement, things began improving 200 years ago in rich countries, 50 years in poor countries.
  • Fewer people die of famine than in earlier centuries.
  • The real prices of food and other raw materials, showing increased natural-resource availability rather than scarcity, began dropping rapidly in the last 200 years.
  • The major air and water pollution in the advanced countries has been lessening rather than worsening, particularly in the last 40 years.
  • Maximum transport speeds have zoomed upwards in the last 200 years, and in the mid-19th century, maximum message speeds went from 30 miles an hour to the speed of an electrical impulse.
  • Income and wealth rose above subsistence for more than a small minority for the first time in human history, beginning 200 years ago.

Many assert that these benign trends cannot continue indefinitely because of some physical limit. One supposed limit is the land area for agriculture. But this constraint may well be loosening rather than tightening, and less land may be needed even as population continues to grow, making more land available for recreation and wilderness. Best commercial practice now uses land millions of times more efficiently that did early humans. On a single acre (0.4 hectare) a hydroponic farm using artificial light raises a ton of food every day, enough to feed a thousand people. And if land were to become more expensive, one could choose to build the factory 100 stories high rather than a single story, and multiply the output per acre by 100. And so on, without practical limit.

Another candidate limit is the quantity of raw materials such as copper. Biologists deride as "alchemy" the notion that these quantities could be augmented by transmuting one element into another. But physicists know that there is no physical impossibility, only a cost factor. Besides, the declining real costs of all raw materials make transmutation unnecessary in the foreseeable future.

Another commonly-mentioned limit is energy, and the Second Law of Thermodynamics is cited. But the Second Law is only meaningful within some bounded space. And it is quite clear that the relevant bounded space includes our sun, whose lifetime is not relevant on an human time-scale.

To epitomize the matter, I have a standing offer to wager a week's or month's pay that any trend in material human welfare will improve rather than get worse. You pick the trend, the country, and the future year. Anything I win goes to fund research.

Some ecologists criticize economists' thinking about limits because it seems to violate common sense. "[To] a scientist [these ideas] are in the same class as the idea that Jack Frost is responsible for ice-crystal patterns on a cold window," writes Paul Ehrlich. He laments the "blunders... economists... commit when they attempt to deal with problems of population, resources, and environment."

Economists think that the whole world is just a market system, and that free goods are infinitely supplied. They are a discipline built on transparent mistakes, from the point of view of a physicist or a biologist.

betrliveIn the economics of population growth, as in physics, common sense can lead one astray. Indeed, common sense is more dangerous here than in physics because one is less willing to acknowledge that one's daily experience does not apply than with respect to high speeds or small particles. With natural resources, for example" it makes perfect sense that there is a fixed stock of them; as some are used up there must be less left. Yet, the economic scarcity of a resource is defined by its price _ and natural resources become less and less scarce economically with every passing decade and century.

The theory of impending scarcity is falsified by all the data from the past. And across-nations comparisons do not show a negative effect of population growth upon economic growth; population density is even correlated positively with economic growth. If physicists will inspect and respect the data, perhaps they will reject the discredited common-sense theory - first-edition Malthusianism based on fixed physical limits, a theory that Malthus himself abandoned in his second and subsequent editions. As the great 19th century economist F.Y. Edgeworth noted: "The treating as constant what is variable is the source of most of the fallacies in Political Economy."

The following theory fits the data: Population growth and increase of income expand demand, forcing up prices of natural resources. The increased prices and the opportunities for productive research trigger the search for new supplies. Most seekers fail, but eventually some succeed, and new sources and substitutes are found. These discoveries leave humanity better off than if the shortages had not occurred. Hence human beings create more than they destroy, on balance.

Bob Park asked: "Doomsayers often preface their warnings with 'if we don't take steps to prevent it.' Is it possible that their warnings have helped produce a better environment?" I answer: Those who warn against real trouble help. Even if the warning is wrong, I do not criticize unless the warner is willfully ignorant or dishonest. But some forecasts are knowingly exaggerated or false. Atmospheric scientist Stephen Schneider says:

"Scientist should consider stretching the truth to get some broad base support, to capture the public's imagination. That, of course, entails getting loads of media coverage. So we have to offer up scary scenarios, make simplified, dramatic statements, and make little mention about any doubts we might have... Each of us has to decide what the right balance is between being effective and being honest."

I know of no evidence that false warnings of doom on balance are beneficial. And in the absence of such evidence, I continue to believe that professing the truth is humanity's best hope.

Julian L. Simon is a Professor in the College of Business and Management at the University of Maryland, College Park. He is editor of The State of Humanity (Basil Blackwell, 1996).

©1995 - 2024, AMERICAN PHYSICAL SOCIETY
APS encourages the redistribution of the materials included in this newspaper provided that attribution to the source is noted and the materials are not truncated or changed.

Editor: Barrett H. Ripin

March 1996 (Volume 5, Number 3)

APS News Home

Issue Table of Contents

APS News Archives

Contact APS News Editor


Articles in this Issue
APS Elementary Institute was a Blizzard of Activity
APS Council Elects 180 New Fellows
Inside the Beltway
Physicists to be Honored at 1996 March Meeting
Book Review
AIP Issues Study on PhD Physicists in National Laboratories
Letters
APS Views
We Must Protect U.S. Investment in Scientific Knowledge
The Back Page
Cartoon